Jigawa plantation and land compensation

I am very keen about real-sector development as engine of growth. When the idea of huge foreign private investment in Jigawa’s agricultural landscape was fi rst muted in 2012, I followed the policy-syntax and dynamics and read other documentations there from. I welcome every good policy of the government in so far as it conforms to achieving ‘Pareto solution’ that would make Jigawans the ultimate benefi ciaries.

I have taken a dispassionate evaluation of this very issue following Hon. Sani Zoro’s outburst of incremental lamentation in a squalid exercise of his legislative oversight. According to Mr. Zorro, the development will dispossess more than 10,000 peasant farmers of their farm lands in over 35 farming communities in Gagarawa Local Government of his constituency.

“Th e company plans to grow sugar cane against the will of majority of the people who own farmlands. Th ere is tension and threats of breakdown of law and order in the area, consequent upon the company’s audacity to proceed with an illegal compensation since Tuesday, November10.

Th is is in spite of a law suit and stiff resistance by owners of the farmlands. We cannot build our nation if we continue to elevate the citizens of other nations above our own citizens,” Zorro said. In a swift reaction recently, the Jigawa State deputy governor, Barrister Ibrahim Hassan Hadejia said: “Out of the 12,000 hectares granted to Mr. Lee in 2013, we now gave him only 6,000 hectares and told him you are going to pay for 12,000 hectares. 6,000 hectares will be exclusively for your use while the balance 6,000 hectares will be curved into plots of lands.

Anybody whose land was aff ected on the acquisition will be allotted a piece of land where he can grow sugarcane for you on an out-grower basis and not only that in-between the rows of sugarcane in the out grower plots you will create a gap for their inter-cropping.” One can see good economics and bad politics being interspersed by the people’s ignorance.

I think the government has not done enough in communicating her policy to the locals whose land is being threatened by this good-intentioned investment policy. Th is is a case of communication gap between the poor farmers and the government. And this is where my intervention in this article becomes imperative. Total Economic Value (TEV) of a hectare of land is given by its use and non-use values. Its use values are represented by its Direct Use Value (DUV), Indirect Use Value (IUV) and its Option Values (OV). Its non-use values are represented by its Existence Value (EV). Th is can be expressed by the formula: TEV = DUV + IUV + OV + VE.

Th is formula allows estimating an approximate value of land; thus, it allows governments to determine the monetary value of gains and losses caused by a land forfeiture- impact, which in this case relates to an increase or decrease of customary land ownership by the local farmers. Th e issue of land compensation is taking another dimension as the Jigawa State Government is clueless.

Th e social and Economic Impact Assessment conducted on the project indicated that a farmer with two hectares would make a minimum of 350 percent of his annual income from the sugarcane cultivation In Nigeria, land is public property. Both urban and rural land is available for investment on leasehold basis. Lease right over land can be transferred, mortgaged or sub-leased together with on-build facilities. Th e period of lease may also be renewed. Th e rental value and the lease period of rural land are determined and fi xed by land use regulations of each state.

Experiences of existing sugar factories in Northern Nigeria show that because of the suitable soil, adequate water and conducive climate, an average sugar cane production per hectare per month of the land under irrigation is very high as compared to other regions and this would make Jigawa State a very attractive location for investors to invest in the production of sugar cane for which it has a comparative advantage. For instance, in 2007, FDI to sub-Saharan Africa amounted to over US$ 30 billion, a new record level – up from the records of about US$ 22 billion in 2006 and US$ 17 billion in 2005.

Th e distribution of FDI fl ows and stocks is highly uneven, shaped by cross-country diff erences in resource endowments. Big shares of investment are concentrated in countries with important petroleum and mineral resources, such as Nigeria.

In Nigeria, Friends of Earth for Africa and Friends of Earth for Europe (2010) noted that most lands grabbed in Nigeria were profi t driven and were under the guises of using the lands acquired for agricultural investments especially for cassava, sugarcane and sweet sorghum which ultimately would become raw materials for bio-fuel production.

However, the Jigawa State Government should as a matter of responsibility, balance investment protection with local interests in order to douse tensions between investment confi dentiality and local oversight in investment arbitration. We must reconcile the investor’s need for regulatory stability with host community’s endemic fear of domestic re-colonization in any land deal. Th is is to ensure that the goal of attracting direct foreign investment in sugar cane farming under the current globalization and liberalization policies of Nigeria is not jeopardized. Hadejia is Acting Registrar NOUN, Gusau Study Centre, Zamfara state

Leave a Reply